By
Randeep
Wadehra
It is surprising that the powers
that be have not given agriculture the importance that it deserves. So focused
have been our policymakers on such big ticket economic issues as PSU
disinvestments, spectrum allocations etc that one fact has been ignored, viz., ever
since independence all our economic planning has been based on the premise –
justified though it has been – that India’s is an agricultural economy. A vast
majority of the country’s population depends upon agriculture for a living – a
constant feature despite the industrialization and globalization that have been
taking place since 1991. Agriculture may contribute only 21% (15% according to
a World Bank report) of India’s GDP, but its importance is due to the fact
that about 72% of the people still live in the villages, a large number of
whom are poor, and the majority among them depends on rain-fed agriculture, or
the increasingly dwindling forests, for their livelihoods.
There have been significant
improvements in agricultural productivity over the decades. When the Borlaug
seed-fertilizer technology was introduced during the mid-1960s the growth in
India’s agricultural output began to gradually catch up with its population
growth rate, and eventually outpaced it. Unsurprisingly, the technology became
our main strategy for increasing food and agricultural output. From the period
1962-65 to the beginning of 1990s, before the initiation of economic reforms in
1991, the agricultural policy operated within a planned economic framework. The
strategy of agricultural development constituted a part and parcel of the
overall planning of the Indian economy. The Plan outlays accorded priority to
public investment in rural infrastructure in general, and in irrigation in
particular. Substantial resources were invested in large, medium and minor
irrigation projects in both the central and state plans.
However, the gains of new
technology were not spread evenly throughout various states and regions of the
country. Moreover, several experts – including environmentalists like Vandana
Shiva – have pointed out that the Green Revolution may have significantly
increased the outputs of wheat and rice, but at the cost of domestic output of
pulses and oilseeds, among other crops. This study, too, admits that the
introduction of Borlaug technology increased the yield levels of mainly wheat,
and later, rice. Policymakers laid great stress upon agricultural R&D and
extension services. A number of agricultural universities were established
under the aegis of the Indian Council of Agricultural Research for combining
the functions of education, research and extension. Policies were formulated to
provide cheap institutional credit and subsidies to encourage farmers to invest
in irrigation, including tanks, pump-sets and irrigation structures. Both
irrigation and power tariffs were hugely subsidized. However, if you look at
the overall rate of agricultural growth – 3% – it is really not impressive by
any standards, and lends credence to the arguments presented by Vandana Shiva
and other likeminded experts that one set of crops prospered at the cost of
another set of crops, which were equally vital to the Indian economy’s health.
A major obsession that has been
guiding our agricultural price policy is to somehow keep food prices low in the
interest of food security, which is sought to be ensured by augmenting domestic
production although imports of such items as sugar, edible oils and even food grains
have become quite frequent over a period of time. But, we have seen how the
pricing policy has manifestly failed to ensure even a modicum of food security.
In fact, it has neither benefited the majority of farmers – who have small to
marginal land holdings – nor has managed to keep the food prices down. Our
present high inflation rates are largely, if not primarily, due to the rising
food prices.
Actually, the current regime of
agriculture pricing and subsidies has helped only rich farmers, while the
majority of the rest don’t even get the benefits of such pricing policies. There
is a need to revisit the entire structure of agricultural pricing and overall
management of its growth. You cannot increase output merely by raising prices;
it is becoming increasingly clear that multiple cropping, non-synthetic
fertilizers as well as non-toxic methods of pest control need to have a serious
relook for long term agricultural prospects in the country.
In the recent years there has been a marked slowdown in not
just the agricultural growth but in the overall rural economy’s development.
The reasons are not far to seek. First and foremost is the inadequate
infrastructure and services in rural areas; and whatever is available is of
poor quality. For example, the irrigation infrastructure is deteriorating as
maintenance is become increasingly difficult due to lack of adequate funds;
many projects have been left incomplete. Moreover, public spending is so
focused on subsidies that more important activities like agricultural research
and extension, health and education and, of course, infrastructure development
are being ignored.
Another factor is over-regulation of domestic agricultural trade
has left little scope for entrepreneurial activity, thus killing the incentive
to improve productivity and competitiveness. When even the costs of land,
labour and credit are controlled directly or indirectly by the government
private enterprise is left with little scope to function. For various reasons
including high transaction costs, even today, a large majority of the rural
poor are unable to access credit.
Moreover, there is a need to have a close look at our
natural resource management. About 25% of the country’s population depends upon
forests for its livelihood. The conservationist approach is actually not very
conducive to generating job opportunities for those communities that have
traditionally depended upon forests for their livelihood. A more dynamic
approach, wherein the traditional stakeholders are empowered to harness,
nurture and commercially exploit the forest resources, would have paid rich
dividends in terms of rural poverty alleviation.
Perhaps it is time to have a comprehensive relook at the
manner in which various policies affecting rural economy have been fashioned
and implemented. Equally important is the need for making various government
agencies and bureaucracies at the states as the central level accountable. The
various instruments and structures of governance like local governments etc too
need reforms or, better still, reinvention. But the question is: would the
powers that be show enough imagination, skill and more importantly the spine
for doing this?
Published in the Daily Post dated July 09, 2012
No comments:
Post a Comment